Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry
CIVINS === It is suspected that the lack of commercial shipbuilding available in the US resulting in the consolidation of the US shipbuilding industry as a whole limits the negotiating capacity for the US Navy and promotes suboptimal contracts that continuously produce major cost and production time...
Main Author: | |
---|---|
Other Authors: | |
Published: |
Cambridge, Massachussetts, Massachussetts Institute of Technology
2014
|
Online Access: | http://hdl.handle.net/10945/40209 |
id |
ndltd-nps.edu-oai-calhoun.nps.edu-10945-40209 |
---|---|
record_format |
oai_dc |
spelling |
ndltd-nps.edu-oai-calhoun.nps.edu-10945-402092014-11-27T16:19:40Z Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry Alvarran, Dominic T. de Weck, Oliver L. Thomas, Mark W. Mechanical Engineering CIVINS It is suspected that the lack of commercial shipbuilding available in the US resulting in the consolidation of the US shipbuilding industry as a whole limits the negotiating capacity for the US Navy and promotes suboptimal contracts that continuously produce major cost and production time overruns. Several incentives and contracting strategies are explored to better incentivize, through formal and informal means, the best value for the Navy in the production of large ships. These methods mainly include a sharper focus within the contracts on the scale and alignment of incentives. Some incentives in use in current contracts were found to be counterproductive to the goals of reduced cost, timeliness and quality because of the disproportionate scaling of one goal's incentive over the others. Once the shareline incentive is lost as in the LPD 17 program, there is much less of a need for the shipbuilder to control costs. Also, a redirection of resources spent on smaller incentives in order to increase larger incentives such as larger order quantitites is suggested. These improvements, however, might only lead to a marginal effect in contract efficiency at best. In order to produce a larger effect, the competitive base in the shipbuilding industry must be increased. This increase in the competitive base is possible through a large capital investment into an existing tier 2 shipyard in order to increase its production capabilities to a tier 1 shipyard. 2014-04-03T18:21:52Z 2014-04-03T18:21:52Z 2013-06 Thesis http://hdl.handle.net/10945/40209 This publication is a work of the U.S. Government as defined in Title 17, United States Code, Section 101. As such, it is in the public domain, and under the provisions of Title 17, United States Code, Section 105, it may not be copyrighted. Cambridge, Massachussetts, Massachussetts Institute of Technology |
collection |
NDLTD |
sources |
NDLTD |
description |
CIVINS === It is suspected that the lack of commercial shipbuilding available in the US resulting in the consolidation of the US shipbuilding industry as a whole limits the negotiating capacity for the US Navy and promotes suboptimal contracts that continuously produce major cost and production time overruns. Several incentives and contracting strategies are explored to better incentivize, through formal and informal means, the best value for the Navy in the production of large ships. These methods mainly include a sharper focus within the contracts on the scale and alignment of incentives. Some incentives in use in current contracts were found to be counterproductive to the goals of reduced cost, timeliness and quality because of the disproportionate scaling of one goal's incentive over the others. Once the shareline incentive is lost as in the LPD 17 program, there is much less of a need for the shipbuilder to control costs. Also, a redirection of resources spent on smaller incentives in order to increase larger incentives such as larger order quantitites is suggested. These improvements, however, might only lead to a marginal effect in contract efficiency at best. In order to produce a larger effect, the competitive base in the shipbuilding industry must be increased. This increase in the competitive base is possible through a large capital investment into an existing tier 2 shipyard in order to increase its production capabilities to a tier 1 shipyard. |
author2 |
de Weck, Oliver L. |
author_facet |
de Weck, Oliver L. Alvarran, Dominic T. |
author |
Alvarran, Dominic T. |
spellingShingle |
Alvarran, Dominic T. Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
author_sort |
Alvarran, Dominic T. |
title |
Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
title_short |
Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
title_full |
Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
title_fullStr |
Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
title_full_unstemmed |
Realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the US shipbuilding industry |
title_sort |
realigining contract incentives for the non-competititive environment of the us shipbuilding industry |
publisher |
Cambridge, Massachussetts, Massachussetts Institute of Technology |
publishDate |
2014 |
url |
http://hdl.handle.net/10945/40209 |
work_keys_str_mv |
AT alvarrandominict realiginingcontractincentivesforthenoncompetititiveenvironmentoftheusshipbuildingindustry |
_version_ |
1716725634248474624 |