Approval Voting in Box Societies

Under approval voting, every voter may vote for any number of canditates. To model approval voting, we let a political spectrum be the set of all possible political positions, and let each voter have a subset of the spectrum that they approve, called an approval region. The fraction of all voters...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Author: Eschenfeldt, Patrick
Format: Others
Published: Scholarship @ Claremont 2012
Subjects:
Online Access:https://scholarship.claremont.edu/hmc_theses/36
https://scholarship.claremont.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1035&context=hmc_theses
id ndltd-CLAREMONT-oai-scholarship.claremont.edu-hmc_theses-1035
record_format oai_dc
spelling ndltd-CLAREMONT-oai-scholarship.claremont.edu-hmc_theses-10352019-10-16T03:06:13Z Approval Voting in Box Societies Eschenfeldt, Patrick Under approval voting, every voter may vote for any number of canditates. To model approval voting, we let a political spectrum be the set of all possible political positions, and let each voter have a subset of the spectrum that they approve, called an approval region. The fraction of all voters who approve the most popular position is the agreement proportion for the society. We consider voting in societies whose political spectrum is modeled by $d$-dimensional space ($\mathbb{R}^d$) with approval regions defined by axis-parallel boxes. For such societies, we first consider a Tur&#aacute;n-type problem, attempting to find the maximum agreement between pairs of voters for a society with a given level of overall agreement. We prove a lower bound on this maximum agreement and find in the literature a proof that the lower bound is optimal. By this result we find that for sufficiently large $n$, any $n$-voter box society in $\mathbb{R}^d$ where at least $\alpha\binom{n}{2}$ pairs of voters agree on some position must have a position contained in $\beta n$ approval regions, where $\alpha = 1-(1-\beta)^2/d$. We also consider an extension of this problem involving projections of approval regions to axes. Finally we consider the question of $(k,m)$-agreeable box societies, where a society is said to be $(k, m)$-agreeable if among every $m$ voters, some $k$ approve a common position. In the $m = 2k - 1$ case, we use methods from graph theory to prove that the agreement proportion is at least $(2d)^{-1}$ for any integer $k \ge 2.$ 2012-05-31T07:00:00Z text application/pdf https://scholarship.claremont.edu/hmc_theses/36 https://scholarship.claremont.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1035&context=hmc_theses © Patrick Eschenfeldt http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/ HMC Senior Theses Scholarship @ Claremont 05C90 Applications 91B72 Spatial Models 05C35 Extremal Problems
collection NDLTD
format Others
sources NDLTD
topic 05C90 Applications
91B72 Spatial Models
05C35 Extremal Problems
spellingShingle 05C90 Applications
91B72 Spatial Models
05C35 Extremal Problems
Eschenfeldt, Patrick
Approval Voting in Box Societies
description Under approval voting, every voter may vote for any number of canditates. To model approval voting, we let a political spectrum be the set of all possible political positions, and let each voter have a subset of the spectrum that they approve, called an approval region. The fraction of all voters who approve the most popular position is the agreement proportion for the society. We consider voting in societies whose political spectrum is modeled by $d$-dimensional space ($\mathbb{R}^d$) with approval regions defined by axis-parallel boxes. For such societies, we first consider a Tur&#aacute;n-type problem, attempting to find the maximum agreement between pairs of voters for a society with a given level of overall agreement. We prove a lower bound on this maximum agreement and find in the literature a proof that the lower bound is optimal. By this result we find that for sufficiently large $n$, any $n$-voter box society in $\mathbb{R}^d$ where at least $\alpha\binom{n}{2}$ pairs of voters agree on some position must have a position contained in $\beta n$ approval regions, where $\alpha = 1-(1-\beta)^2/d$. We also consider an extension of this problem involving projections of approval regions to axes. Finally we consider the question of $(k,m)$-agreeable box societies, where a society is said to be $(k, m)$-agreeable if among every $m$ voters, some $k$ approve a common position. In the $m = 2k - 1$ case, we use methods from graph theory to prove that the agreement proportion is at least $(2d)^{-1}$ for any integer $k \ge 2.$
author Eschenfeldt, Patrick
author_facet Eschenfeldt, Patrick
author_sort Eschenfeldt, Patrick
title Approval Voting in Box Societies
title_short Approval Voting in Box Societies
title_full Approval Voting in Box Societies
title_fullStr Approval Voting in Box Societies
title_full_unstemmed Approval Voting in Box Societies
title_sort approval voting in box societies
publisher Scholarship @ Claremont
publishDate 2012
url https://scholarship.claremont.edu/hmc_theses/36
https://scholarship.claremont.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1035&context=hmc_theses
work_keys_str_mv AT eschenfeldtpatrick approvalvotinginboxsocieties
_version_ 1719268821216264192