Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy

Since the establishment of commercial sharing economy services like Uber, Blablacar, Lyft, Airbnb, TaskRabbit, etc., the debate about the sharing economy and its effects on competition has generated lively discussions, which have too often dangerously departed from a debate based on objective (marke...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Authors: Francesco Russo, Maria Luisa Stasi
Format: Article
Language:English
Published: Alexander von Humboldt Institute for Internet and Society 2016-06-01
Series:Internet Policy Review
Online Access:https://policyreview.info/node/418
id doaj-cfb5bf9c6073442f8c667f8a8f4c0db3
record_format Article
spelling doaj-cfb5bf9c6073442f8c667f8a8f4c0db32020-11-25T02:47:02ZengAlexander von Humboldt Institute for Internet and SocietyInternet Policy Review2197-67752016-06-01Volume 5Issue 210.14763/2016.2.418Defining the relevant market in the sharing economyFrancesco Russo0Maria Luisa Stasi1University of AmsterdamEuropean University InstituteSince the establishment of commercial sharing economy services like Uber, Blablacar, Lyft, Airbnb, TaskRabbit, etc., the debate about the sharing economy and its effects on competition has generated lively discussions, which have too often dangerously departed from a debate based on objective (market) observation to evolve into a quarrel among the supporters and opponents of the online platforms. Undoubtedly, the peculiar features of these new firms’ business models create frictions with the traditional regulatory environment, which currently appears to be incapable of framing them into models and schemes typical of a previous economic phase, such as, for example, one-sided markets, no externalities, and competition mainly on price. Nevertheless, setting aside the more or less impromptu debate about the “social goodness” of these firms, we argue that competition enforcers should look at their effective market power. In fact, as the basic principles of competition law teach us, only when those firms have (more or less legitimate) significant market power, will they be subject to special responsibilities and to stringent restrictions and obligations. Toward this aim, it is first necessary to define the relevant market. And, immediately afterwards, to delimit firms’ market position. This, in turn, should help to assess their compliance with the competition rules and the obligations that they are – or rather that they should be – subjected to. This exercise is not an easy one because the traditional regulatory concepts and definitions do not seem to reflect the competition dynamics that characterise the new markets on which we are reflecting. In this paper we focus on a number of challenges that are posed by the sharing economy businesses, suggesting that they could be solved with the traditional competition instruments, although adapted to the peculiar features of the markets that are at stake. These include, among others, multi-sidedness and the presence of different externalities.https://policyreview.info/node/418
collection DOAJ
language English
format Article
sources DOAJ
author Francesco Russo
Maria Luisa Stasi
spellingShingle Francesco Russo
Maria Luisa Stasi
Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
Internet Policy Review
author_facet Francesco Russo
Maria Luisa Stasi
author_sort Francesco Russo
title Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
title_short Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
title_full Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
title_fullStr Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
title_full_unstemmed Defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
title_sort defining the relevant market in the sharing economy
publisher Alexander von Humboldt Institute for Internet and Society
series Internet Policy Review
issn 2197-6775
publishDate 2016-06-01
description Since the establishment of commercial sharing economy services like Uber, Blablacar, Lyft, Airbnb, TaskRabbit, etc., the debate about the sharing economy and its effects on competition has generated lively discussions, which have too often dangerously departed from a debate based on objective (market) observation to evolve into a quarrel among the supporters and opponents of the online platforms. Undoubtedly, the peculiar features of these new firms’ business models create frictions with the traditional regulatory environment, which currently appears to be incapable of framing them into models and schemes typical of a previous economic phase, such as, for example, one-sided markets, no externalities, and competition mainly on price. Nevertheless, setting aside the more or less impromptu debate about the “social goodness” of these firms, we argue that competition enforcers should look at their effective market power. In fact, as the basic principles of competition law teach us, only when those firms have (more or less legitimate) significant market power, will they be subject to special responsibilities and to stringent restrictions and obligations. Toward this aim, it is first necessary to define the relevant market. And, immediately afterwards, to delimit firms’ market position. This, in turn, should help to assess their compliance with the competition rules and the obligations that they are – or rather that they should be – subjected to. This exercise is not an easy one because the traditional regulatory concepts and definitions do not seem to reflect the competition dynamics that characterise the new markets on which we are reflecting. In this paper we focus on a number of challenges that are posed by the sharing economy businesses, suggesting that they could be solved with the traditional competition instruments, although adapted to the peculiar features of the markets that are at stake. These include, among others, multi-sidedness and the presence of different externalities.
url https://policyreview.info/node/418
work_keys_str_mv AT francescorusso definingtherelevantmarketinthesharingeconomy
AT marialuisastasi definingtherelevantmarketinthesharingeconomy
_version_ 1724755198552834048