Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity

Contrary to the presumption common in the social sciences, that culture and rationality are in opposition and mutually exclusive of each other - a presumption shared by such different approaches as game theory, rational choice theory and cultural anthropology - , the author emphazises that cu...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Author: Theodore M. Porter
Format: Article
Language:deu
Published: StudienVerlag 1996-01-01
Series:Österreichische Zeitschrift für Geschichtswissenschaften
Online Access:https://journals.univie.ac.at/index.php/oezg/article/view/5643
id doaj-955e4e7d6a454597a6569af504609787
record_format Article
spelling doaj-955e4e7d6a454597a6569af5046097872021-03-18T20:49:55ZdeuStudienVerlagÖsterreichische Zeitschrift für Geschichtswissenschaften1016-765X2707-966X1996-01-017210.25365/oezg-1996-7-2-2Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of ObjectivityTheodore M. Porter0University of California, Los Angeles, Department of History Contrary to the presumption common in the social sciences, that culture and rationality are in opposition and mutually exclusive of each other - a presumption shared by such different approaches as game theory, rational choice theory and cultural anthropology - , the author emphazises that cultures always have their own rationalities. Standards of reasonableness cannot be thought of as universal, but inevitably reflect culture. Rationality is conditioned, so the author argues, by political forms, economic circumstances, institutions, laws, and customs. This is also true for cultures of objectivity, which are based on the rejection of what is usually conceived of as subjective, linked to emotions and to the personal. The examples of the historic struggles relating to the profession of accountants and the invention of cost-benefit analysis in the United States enable the author to put forward the argument that the quest for objectivity is in itself the cultural expression of a need emerging within societies where political order is not self- evident. Not only bureaucracies impose general standards of administration to avoid severe political conflicts, but various outsiders in different spheres of a society try and manage to gain credibility by escaping what is tainted by personal interest and subjectivity. From this perspective, the author identifies the insistence on impersonal rules in science as a cultural response to conditions of distrust within the corresponding disciplines and in the larger society, and discusses the uses made of statistics in the social sciences characterised by the reduction of quantification to impersonal, unitary, almost mechanical, strategies of analysis. https://journals.univie.ac.at/index.php/oezg/article/view/5643
collection DOAJ
language deu
format Article
sources DOAJ
author Theodore M. Porter
spellingShingle Theodore M. Porter
Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
Österreichische Zeitschrift für Geschichtswissenschaften
author_facet Theodore M. Porter
author_sort Theodore M. Porter
title Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
title_short Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
title_full Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
title_fullStr Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
title_full_unstemmed Statistics, Social Science, and the Culture of Objectivity
title_sort statistics, social science, and the culture of objectivity
publisher StudienVerlag
series Österreichische Zeitschrift für Geschichtswissenschaften
issn 1016-765X
2707-966X
publishDate 1996-01-01
description Contrary to the presumption common in the social sciences, that culture and rationality are in opposition and mutually exclusive of each other - a presumption shared by such different approaches as game theory, rational choice theory and cultural anthropology - , the author emphazises that cultures always have their own rationalities. Standards of reasonableness cannot be thought of as universal, but inevitably reflect culture. Rationality is conditioned, so the author argues, by political forms, economic circumstances, institutions, laws, and customs. This is also true for cultures of objectivity, which are based on the rejection of what is usually conceived of as subjective, linked to emotions and to the personal. The examples of the historic struggles relating to the profession of accountants and the invention of cost-benefit analysis in the United States enable the author to put forward the argument that the quest for objectivity is in itself the cultural expression of a need emerging within societies where political order is not self- evident. Not only bureaucracies impose general standards of administration to avoid severe political conflicts, but various outsiders in different spheres of a society try and manage to gain credibility by escaping what is tainted by personal interest and subjectivity. From this perspective, the author identifies the insistence on impersonal rules in science as a cultural response to conditions of distrust within the corresponding disciplines and in the larger society, and discusses the uses made of statistics in the social sciences characterised by the reduction of quantification to impersonal, unitary, almost mechanical, strategies of analysis.
url https://journals.univie.ac.at/index.php/oezg/article/view/5643
work_keys_str_mv AT theodoremporter statisticssocialscienceandthecultureofobjectivity
_version_ 1724215032093343744